Showing posts with label credit ratings. Show all posts
Showing posts with label credit ratings. Show all posts
Saturday, June 10, 2023
I asked OpenAI:
"Current risk weighted bank capital requirements are based on what’s perceived as risky is more dangerous to bank systems than what’s perceived as safe. How does that square with that the large bank exposures that detonated major bank crises were all built-up with what’s perceived as safe?"
OpenAI answered:
"You bring up an important point regarding the perception of risk in the banking system and its relationship to major bank crises. It is true that historically, some major bank crises have been associated with exposures that were considered "safe" or low risk according to prevailing perceptions at the time. This phenomenon is often referred to as the "risk paradox" or "risk perception problem."
One reason behind this risk paradox is that risk perceptions in the banking industry can be influenced by various factors, including market conditions, prevailing economic assumptions, and regulatory frameworks. These perceptions may not always accurately reflect the true underlying risks associated with certain assets or activities. As a result, banks and regulators may focus on addressing the perceived risks while overlooking or underestimating the potential risks embedded in seemingly safe assets or activities.
In the context of risk-weighted capital requirements, the challenge lies in the accurate assessment and calibration of risk weights assigned to different assets. If risk weights do not adequately capture the true risk of an asset, it can create a discrepancy between the perceived risk and the actual risk. This can lead to unintended consequences, such as the excessive allocation of credit to assets with lower perceived risks but higher actual risks.
Furthermore, financial innovations and complex financial products can further complicate risk assessments. These products often involve multiple layers of risk and interdependencies, making it difficult to accurately capture their true risk profiles. In such cases, there is a risk of underestimating the risks associated with these products, leading to potential vulnerabilities in the banking system.
It is worth noting that regulators and standard-setting bodies, such as the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, continuously work to improve risk measurement methodologies and enhance the accuracy of risk-weighted capital requirements. For example, Basel III introduced more stringent rules for risk measurement, capital buffers, and stress testing to address some of these issues.
However, it is important to acknowledge that risk measurement and regulation in banking are complex tasks, and there will always be inherent limitations in capturing all risks accurately. The banking industry and regulators must remain vigilant, regularly reassess their risk models and frameworks, and learn from past crises to continually improve risk management practices and enhance financial stability.
In conclusion, the risk paradox you highlighted underscores the challenges in accurately assessing and managing risks in the banking system. The perception of safety can sometimes be deceptive, and the industry must remain attentive to the potential risks embedded in seemingly safe assets or activities. Ongoing efforts are necessary to improve risk measurement methodologies, enhance risk management practices, and strengthen regulatory frameworks to minimize the likelihood and impact of major bank crises."
I asked OpenAI:
"Do you know of any major bank crisis caused by large bank exposures built-up with assets perceived as risky?"
OpenAI answered:
"Yes, there have been major bank crises caused by large bank exposures built-up with assets perceived as risky. One prominent example is the global financial crisis of 2008, which was triggered by the collapse of the U.S. subprime mortgage market.
In the years leading up to the crisis, financial institutions accumulated significant exposures to mortgage-backed securities (MBS) and related derivatives. These assets were often perceived as relatively risky due to their connection to subprime mortgages, which were home loans extended to borrowers with weaker credit histories. However, these assets were also considered to carry low risk according to prevailing risk models and credit rating agencies.
Financial institutions, including major banks, invested heavily in these mortgage-backed securities, often leveraging their positions. They believed that the risk of default on these assets was low due to assumptions that housing prices would continue to rise and that the risks were adequately diversified through securitization and credit derivatives.
However, when the U.S. housing market experienced a significant downturn, many subprime borrowers defaulted on their mortgage payments. This led to a rapid and severe decline in the value of mortgage-backed securities, triggering substantial losses for banks and other financial institutions. The interconnectedness of the global financial system exacerbated the crisis, as losses in one institution or market spread throughout the system.
The global financial crisis demonstrated how large exposures to assets perceived as risky, but treated as safe in risk models and ratings, can have severe consequences for the banking system. It exposed the limitations of risk assessment models and highlighted the potential for systemic risk when institutions heavily rely on assets with underappreciated risks.
It is important to note that the crisis was not solely caused by exposures to perceived risky assets, but also by a range of other factors such as lax lending standards, inadequate risk management, complex financial products, and the interconnectedness of global financial markets. Nonetheless, the misperception and underestimation of risks associated with assets considered risky played a significant role in the crisis."
I asked OpenAI:
"Lower bank capital requirements against what’s perceived as safe than against what’s perceived as risky, does that increase the dangers of what is known as the “risk paradox?"
OpenAI answered:
"Lower bank capital requirements against assets perceived as safe compared to those perceived as risky can indeed contribute to the risk paradox and increase the dangers associated with it. This is because such a regulatory framework can create incentives for banks to allocate a larger portion of their portfolios towards assets deemed safe, even if those assets carry hidden or underestimated risks.
When capital requirements are lower for assets perceived as safe, banks have a financial incentive to hold more of these assets in order to optimize their capital ratios. This can lead to an overemphasis on assets with lower risk weights, as they allow banks to achieve higher capital efficiency. However, as we have seen in the past, the perception of safety does not always align with the true underlying risks.
The risk paradox arises when banks and regulators focus on addressing the perceived risks rather than accurately assessing the actual risks associated with various assets or activities. By assigning lower capital requirements to assets perceived as safe, the regulatory framework may unintentionally encourage banks to allocate credit towards these assets without fully accounting for their hidden or underestimated risks.
The dangers of the risk paradox are amplified when seemingly safe assets turn out to be riskier than expected. This can happen due to various factors, such as sudden changes in market conditions, unforeseen interdependencies, or flaws in risk assessment models. If a significant number of banks hold large exposures to such risky assets, it can create systemic vulnerabilities and increase the potential for widespread financial distress.
To mitigate the dangers of the risk paradox, it is crucial for regulators to continuously reassess and improve risk assessment methodologies and capital requirements. This includes regularly reviewing and updating risk weights assigned to different asset classes based on a thorough understanding of their true underlying risks. Additionally, stress testing and scenario analysis can help identify vulnerabilities and ensure that banks are adequately capitalized against various risk scenarios.
The regulatory framework should also promote a holistic and comprehensive approach to risk management that goes beyond relying solely on risk weights. This can include considering factors such as concentration risk, interconnectedness, and the potential for contagion.
By implementing a robust and dynamic regulatory framework that appropriately addresses both perceived and actual risks, regulators can help mitigate the dangers associated with the risk paradox and promote a more resilient banking system."
Note: The answers are copied exactly from those given to me by OpenAI
Sunday, June 4, 2023
ChatGPT- OpenAI: Credit rating agencies, empowered by bank capital/equity requirements, is that a systemic risk?
As an Executive Director at the World Bank, I often warned that assigning some few human fallible credit rating agencies so much power for deciding how much capital/equity banks needed to hold against assets, introduced a huge systemic risk in the financial sector. E.g.:
Given now the opportunity to chat with ChatGPT – OpenAI, I asked:
"Borrowers love great credit ratings as that allows them to borrow more at lower interest rates. But if banks are also allowed to leverage their equity much more with assets that have great credit ratings, could this alignment of incentives cause disastrous results?"
OpenAI answered:
"The alignment of incentives between borrowers and banks regarding credit ratings can indeed create potential risks and contribute to financial instability if not properly regulated. While borrowers benefit from lower interest rates and increased borrowing capacity with excellent credit ratings, banks may be tempted to leverage their equity more with assets that have high credit ratings.
This situation can lead to several problems:
1. Excessive risk-taking: Banks may become overly confident in the safety of assets with high credit ratings and increase their leverage beyond reasonable levels. This behavior can result in a higher concentration of risk within the financial system.
2. Mispricing of risk: If banks rely too heavily on credit ratings without conducting their due diligence, they may underestimate the true risk associated with certain assets. This mispricing can create a false sense of security and lead to the accumulation of risky assets in the banking system.
3. Contagion effect: In the event of a downturn or a shock to the financial system, the interconnectedness of banks and their reliance on highly rated assets can amplify the impact and lead to contagion. If the credit quality of these assets deteriorates, multiple institutions could face severe losses simultaneously.
4. Systemic risk: When a large number of banks engage in excessive leverage based on assets with great credit ratings, the overall stability of the financial system may be compromised. If these assets were to experience a sudden decline in value or suffer from rating downgrades, it could trigger a broader financial crisis.
To mitigate these risks, regulatory measures are necessary. Regulators should ensure that banks have robust risk management frameworks in place and are not solely relying on credit ratings when assessing the quality and risk of assets. Strengthening capital and liquidity requirements can also enhance the resilience of banks and mitigate the potential negative effects of excessive leverage.
Moreover, improving the accuracy and transparency of credit ratings and reducing conflicts of interest in the rating process can contribute to a more reliable assessment of risk. This would help prevent a situation where banks overly rely on ratings without conducting their independent analysis.
Overall, it is crucial to strike a balance between encouraging lending and maintaining the stability of the financial system."
Wednesday, August 31, 2022
The (Odious) Bank Credit Redistribution Act: The Great Financialization
1988 Basel I: Risk weighted bank capital requirements with decreed weights: 0% government, 50% residential mortgages and 100% the rest, e.g., small businesses and entrepreneurs; all as if bureaucrats know better what to with credit, for which repayment they’re not personally responsible for than e.g., small businesses and entrepreneurs; all as if financing the purchase of a house is more important than financing those who can create the jobs, the incomes, by which repay mortgages and service utilities.
Why? “Assets assigned the lowest risk, for which bank capital requirements were therefore nonexistent or low, were what had the most political support: sovereign credits & home mortgages” Paul Volcker
2004 Basel II: The introduction of the systemic risk of bank capital requirements depending hugely on human fallible credit rating agencies. To top it up the decreed weights e.g., 20% AAA to AA fated – 150% below BB- rated, continued to ignore the fact that all dangerous large bank exposures have always been built up with assets perceived as safe.
2007-2009 A global financial crisis (GFC) caused by excessive exposures to AAA rated mortgage-backed-securities (MBS).
2010 Basel III: Kicking the can forward so as not t be blamed the regulators, trying to mend regulatory blackholes concocted a mishmash of hundreds or regulations. Sadly, these all still leave intact, on the margin, which is where it most counts, the distortion in the allocation of credit produced by the risk weighted capital requirements.
2009… 2022: Job possibilities for bank supervisors and bank supervision responders keeps on booming… and just you wait for the ESG based capital requirements based on ESG ratings.
In short:
Bank capital requirements that so much favor government debts, has empowered Bureaucracy Autocracies all around the world. Central banks’ later Quantitative Easing (QEs), put that assistance on steroids
Bank capital requirements mostly based on perceived credit risks, not on misperceived risks or unexpected events, e.g., pandemic/war, guarantees banks will, sooner or later, stand there naked, just when we need them the most.
Favoring with much lower capital requirements banks holding “safe” government debt and residential mortgages (the present-demand-carbs), than loans to “risky” businesses (the future-supply-proteins), inflates inflation and causes obese - not muscular economic growth.
The Great Financialization, supported by low bank capital requirements, central banks’ QEs, and MMT preaching, produced way too much easy money... manna from heaven. That emptied many churches. Coming Minsky moments will fill these up again.
Extremely short:
Monday, October 18, 2021
But with questions that shall not to be heard, courage might not suffice
“A lot of people want to convince you that you need a Ph.D. or a law degree or dozens of hours of free time to read dense texts about critical theory to understand the woke movement and its worldview. You do not. You simply need to believe your own eyes and ears.”
So begins Bari Weiss’ “We Got Here Because of Cowardice. We Get Out With Courage… Say no to the Woke Revolution”
Indeed:
We should need nothing of that sort in order to understand that… risk weighted bank capital requirements based on that what’s perceived as risky is more dangerous to our bank systems than what’s perceived as safe, is as wrong/as woke as can be.
2004, Basel II assigned to the safest of the perceived safe, a risk weight of 20% and, to the riskiest of the perceived risky, a risk weight of 150%... Translating into a Basel II capital requirement of 1.6.% for the safest and 12% for the riskiest... Meaning banks were allowed by their regulators to leverage their capital 62.5 with assets some few human fallible credit rating agencies consider to be the safest, and 8.3 times with what these agencies consider to be the riskiest.
Should we really agree with that those excessive exposures that could become risky for bank systems are more built up with assets rated below BB- than with assets rated AAA? Does it not suffice to remember the 2008 global financial crisis?
We should need nothing of that sort in order to understand that… decreed risk weights of 0% the government and 100% citizens, de facto implies that bureaucrats know better what to do with credit for which repayment they’re not personally responsible for than e.g., small businesses and entrepreneurs.
Should we agree with such statism/communism/fascism?
We should need nothing of that sort in order to understand that… allowing banks to leverage more their capital with some assets than others, make it easier for them to obtain a higher risk adjusted return on equity with some assets than with other.
Should we agree with such in distortion of the allocation of bank credit?
We should need nothing of that sort in order to understand that… those less creditworthy already get less credit and pay higher interest rates.
Should we agree with bank regulations that declare the less creditworthy to also be less worthy of credit?
We should need nothing of that sort in order to understand that… … and on this issue I could go on and on… like wondering why the Academia says nothing. Might it be an Inquisition has declared questions on this issue shall not be heard?
PS. My 1999 Op-Ed in which, like Bari Weiss, I quote Arthur Koestler. “I automatically learned to classify all that is repugnant as an »inheritance from the past», and all that is attractive as the »seed of the future». With the aid of this automatic classification it was still possible for a European in 1932 to visit Russia and continue to be a communist.”
Saturday, January 30, 2021
And the Academia kept silence.
Note: The Basel Committee’s use of the term “capital” in “risk weighted bank capital requirements” has sowed loads of confusions. Its real significance is “risk weighted bank shareholders’ equity/skin-in-the-game requirements". It has nothing to do with in what bank assets it’s invested.
Note: With the appearance ChatGPT – OpenAI, Academia will be asked much more on the why of its almost total silence on the outright dangerous bank regulations. Just wait until their peer reviewed papers get reviewed by #AI.
“A ship in harbor is safe, but that is not what ships are for”. John A. Shedd, 1928. Does that not apply for banks too?
For about 600 years banks allocated credit based on risk adjusted interest rates. After risk weighted capital requirements were introduced, they allocate it based on risk adjusted returns on regulatory equity (RORE). Huge distortions ensued!
And the Academia kept silence.
The risk weighted bank capital requirements are based on perceived credit risks and not on risks conditioned to how bankers react to perceived risks. Clearly the regulators know nothing about conditional probabilities.
And the Academia kept silence.
And the Academia kept silence.
Lower bank capital requirements when lending to the government than when lending to citizens, de facto implies bureaucrats know better what to do with credit they’re not personally responsible for than e.g. entrepreneurs
And the Academia kept silence.
Lower bank capital requirements for banks when financing the central government than when financing local governments, de facto implies federal bureaucrats know much better what to do with credit than local bureaucrats.
And the Academia kept silence.
Lower bank capital requirements for banks when financing residential mortgages, de facto implies that those buying a house are more important for the economy than, e.g. small businesses and entrepreneurs.
And the Academia kept silence.
Lower bank capital requirements for banks when financing the “safer” present than when financing the “riskier” future, de facto implies placing a reverse mortgage on the current economy and giving up on our grandchildren’s future.
And the Academia kept silence.
And the Academia kept silence.
And all for nothing. Those excessive bank exposures that could be dangerous to our bank systems are always built-up with assets perceived or decreed as safe, and never ever with assets perceived as risky.
And the Academia kept silence.
Could it be that? “One has to belong to the intelligentsia to believe things like that: no ordinary man could be such a fool.” George Orwell
“Assets for which capital requirements were nonexistent, were what had most political support: sovereign credits. A simple ‘leverage ratio’ discouraged holdings of low-return government securities" Paul Volcker
On the Nobel Prize: The Economic Sciences Prize Committee of the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences selects the Nobel prize winner in economic sciences. That prize was established by Sveriges Riksbank in 1968. The current Governor of said central bank, is Stefan Ingves who, from 2011 until 2019, served as the Chairman of the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision.
Could anyone arguing that what’s perceived as safe is much more dangerous to our bank system (heliocentric) than what’s perceived as risky (geocentric), be nominated for that prize by such a (Inquisition) committee?
https://subprimeregulations.blogspot.com/2020/12/how-come-we-ended-up-with-stupid.html
Since we know all about risks, to make your banks safe, we regulators, we the Basel Committee, we give you our risk weighted bank capital requirements. And the Academia (desperately wanting to be counted among the Pigs on Orwell’s farm) kept silence.
http://perkurowski.blogspot.com/2023/05/has-orwells-big-brother-already.html
Saturday, December 7, 2019
Tombstones
Here rests a bank regulator who all his life believed that what bankers perceived as risky was more dangerous to our bank systems than what bankers perceived as safe.
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a bank regulator who based the risk weighted bank capital requirements on bankers perceiving risk correctly, and not on that they could be wrong.
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a regulator who missed his lectures on conditional probabilities, and therefore did not set the risk weighted capital requirements conditioned on how bankers respond to perceived credit risks.
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a regulator who even though bankers respond to perceived credit risks, with size of exposures and risk adjusted interest rates, also wanted bank capital to double up on that same perceived risk
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a bank regulator who never understood the systemic risks he introduced into banking, by for instance assigning so much power to credit rating agencies, or his stress-testings on the stresses a la mode.
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a bank regulator who never understood his own risk aversion and confirmation bias stress, before stress testing banks on the possibility of his own regulations being wrong.
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a bank regulator who for the risk weighted bank capital requirements agreed with risk weights of 20% for dangerous AAA rated and 150% for innocous below BB- rated
May his soul rest in peace.
“A ship in harbor is safe, but that is not what ships are for.” John A. Shedd.
Here rests a bank regulator who caused banks to dangerously overpopulate safe harbors, and sent other investors and small time savers out on the risky oceans.
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a bank regulator who by much favoring banks to finance the "safer" present over the "riskier" future, blocked millions of SMEs' and entrepreneurs' access to bank credit and with it to risk-taking… the oxygen of all development
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a statist bank regulator who believed a government bureaucrat knows better (Risk Weight 0%) what to do with credit he’s not personally responsible for, than an entrepreneur or SME (RW 100%)
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a bank regulator who for risk weighted bank capital requirements agreed with a low 35% risk weight to residential mortgages, which caused houses to morph from affordable homes to risky investment assets.
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a bank regulator with a Ph.D. who proved right Daniel Patrick Moynihan, who supposedly held “There are some mistakes only Ph.Ds. can make.
May his soul rest in peace.
Here lies a central banker who injected huge amounts of liquidity without understanding how risk weighted bank capital requirements distorted the allocation of credit
May his soul rest in peace.
Here lies a financial journalist who scared stiff he would never be invited to WEF in Davos, never questioned the risk weighted bank capital requirements.
May his soul rest in peace.
Here lies an ordinary citizen who wanting so much to believe it true, swallowed lock stock and barrel the regulatory technocrats' populism imbedded in the risk weighted bank capital requirements
May his soul rest in peace.
Here rests a regulator who helped guarantee especially large bank crises, caused by especially large exposures to what’s perceived especially safe and might not be, and is held against especially little capital
May his soul rest...
Here rests a regulator who assisted by his central bank colleagues, helped set horrible Minsky moments on steroids
May his soul rest...
Here rests a regulator who assisted by his central bank colleagues, helped set horrible Minsky moments on steroids
May his soul rest...
Sunday, December 9, 2018
What goes up too much must come down too much. The best countercyclical policy there is, is the elimination of the pro-cyclical ones.
“What goes up must come down, spinning wheel got to go 'round” David Clayton Thomas
Governor Lael Brainard on December 07, 2018, in “Assessing Financial Stability over the Cycle” a speech delivered at the Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington, D.C., said:
“In an economic downturn, widespread downgrades of these low-rated investment-grade bonds to speculative-grade ratings could induce some investors to sell them rapidly--for instance, because lower-rated bonds have higher regulatory capital requirements or because bond funds have limits on the share of non-investment-grade bonds they hold.”
And Brainard then proceeds to extensively describe the advantages of countercyclical capital requirements (CCyB) for building additional resilience in the financial system.
YES...BUT, the other side of the mirror is: In an economic upturn, higher credit ratings of bonds could induce some investors to buy them rapidly--for instance, because higher-rated bonds have lower regulatory capital requirements, or because bond funds have lesser or no limits on investment-grade bonds they hold.
So if that is not procyclical what is?
Therefore, before thinking of using countercyclical capital requirements, which by themselves might be introducing distorting signals, which might make the use of these at the right moment when they are really needed harder, let’s get rid, altogether, of the risk weighted capital requirements for banks. Those, which, by the way, even when the economic cycles are correctly identified, still distort the allocation of bank credit to the real economy.
And since credit ratings were mentioned, in April 2003, at the World Bank I opined:
"Nowadays, when information is just too voluminous and fast to handle, market or authorities have decided to delegate the evaluation of it into the hands of much fewer players such as credit rating agencies. This will introduce systemic risks in the market"
Here is my 2004 letter to the Financial Times, FT, "Towards a counter cyclical Basel?" It was not published
Tuesday, August 28, 2018
Anat Admati explains the financial crisis better than most, but does still not get to the real heart of it.
I refer to Promarket.org and Evonomics.com where Stanford professor Anat Admati discusses her paper“It Takes a Village of Media, Business, Policy, and Academic Experts to Maintain a Dangerous Financial System” May 2016.
In it she explains how a mix of distorted incentives, ignorance, confusion, and lack of accountability contributes to the persistence of a dangerous and poorly regulated financial system.
Here some quotes and comments:
1. “Admati draws a contrast with aviation. Although tens of thousands of airplanes take off and land, often in crowded skies, busy airports, and within short time spans, crashes are remarkably rare. Everyone involved in aviation collaborates to maintain high safety standards”
PK. The main explanation for that is that everything in aviation is considered risky… and there are no aviation regulators giving anyone the excuse of “at this point you can relax”.
2. “When they seek profits banks effectively compete to endanger their depositors and the public. An analogy would be subsidizing trucks to drive at reckless speed even as slower driving would cause fewer accidents.”
PK. Of course allowing reckless speeds, like no limit at all when lending to Greece, and 62.5 times when AAA to AA ratings are present, must cause serious crashes.
But, the worst part of it all is that banks are not allowed to drive all assets at the same speed. As a consequence, being paid on delivery, banks will not go to where they must go slower, like the leverage speed limits that apply when lending to entrepreneurs, and will therefore not perform their vital function of allocating credit efficiently to the economy. The words “the purpose of banks is” are sadly nowhere to be seen in bank regulations.
3. “Politicians, find implicit guarantees attractive because they are an ‘invisible form of subsidy’ that appear free because they do not show up on budgets, as the costs associated are ultimately paid for by the citizenry.”
PK. At this moment the statist regulators and politicians find those “implicit guarantees” especially attractive because of its quid-pro-quo component. “We scratch your back with implicit guarantees and you scratch ours something for which we in 1988, with the Basel Accord assigned to the sovereign a 0% risk weight, and one of 100% to the citizen” And ever since the “good and friendly” sovereigns have had access to subsidized credit… and the regulators have now painted themselves into a corner.
4. “Credit rating agencies, “private watchdogs,” have conflicted interests because they derive revenues from regulated companies as well as sometimes from regulators.”
PK. Yes but notwithstanding that, even if the credit rating agencies have behaved totally independent, there can be little doubt that assigning so much decision power to some few human fallible credit rating agencies would introduce the mother of all systemic risks.
And besides, since bankers already consider risks perceived when deciding on size of exposures and risk premiums to charge, to have perceived risks also reflected in the capital requirements, violates the “Kurowski dixit” rule: “Risks, even when perfectly perceived, leads to the wrong actions, if excessively considered.”
5. “I had expected academics and policy makers to engage and care about whether what they were saying and doing was appropriate, particularly since they often know more than the public about the issues and are entrusted to protect the public”
PK. So had I. They, Anat Admati included, are still not able to explain to regulators about conditional probabilities. And so regulators keep on regulating based on the perceived risk of assets and not based on the risk of assets based on how these are perceived.
In terms of airplanes they regulate based on how the pilots perceive the risks and not based on that the pilots could perceive the wrong risks or act incorrectly when facing the correct risks.
6. “Lawmakers are rarely held accountable for the harmful effect of implicit guarantees combined with poor regulations.”
PK. Yes not one single regulators have been forced to parade down 5thAvenue wearing a dunce cap. On the contrary many of them have been promoted and are still regulating without even considering the possibility they have been mistaken all the time.
PS. Even though Daniel Moynihan is supposed to have opined: “There are some mistakes it takes a Ph.D. to make”, the challenges still remain for the PhDs about what to do with the opinions of the lowlier graduates, like with just an MBA. Do we dare to quote him?
And here my soon 2.800 letters to the Financial Times on this. Am I obsessed? Sure, but so are they ignoring my arguments.
And finally here a humble home-made youtube https://youtu.be/TUdKhm6_a8Y
Monday, March 12, 2018
Charles Goodhart also pointed out the stupidity of risk weighted capital requirements for banks based on ex ante perceived risks… also with no luck!
In the very last page (540) of Charles Goodhart’s “The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision: A history of the Early Years, 1947-1997” of 2011 we read the following:
“Capital is supposed to be a buffer against unexpected loss: In so far as capital is required against unexpected loss, since expected loss should be handled by appropriate interest margins, the use of credit ratings as a guide to risk weights for capital adequacy requirements (CARs) is wrong and inconsistent, since these give a measure of expected loss. What is needed instead is a measure of the uncertainty of such losses, the second moment rather than the first.
If capital risk weights had been based, as they should logically have been, on the uncertainty attending future losses, rather than their expected modal performance, the financial system might have avoided much of the worst disasters of the 2007/08 financial crisis.
It remains surprisingly difficult to persuade regulators of this simple point.”
But to that Goodhart adds “It does however, get recognized from time to time”… though the examples he then indicates, are not so clear.
In the Epilogue (page 581) Goodhart list some of the failings of the BCBS’s regulations:
1. The lack of any theoretical basis.
2. The focus on the individual institution, rather that the system
3. The failure to reach an accord on liquidity;
4. The lack of empirical analysis;
5. The unwillingness to discuss either sanctions or crisis resolution, and so on.
That clearly adds up to a total regulatory failure... no wonder they don't want to discuss sanctions.
But, unfortunately as I see it, Charles Goodhart, though absolutely right, is only scratching the surface. What is most dangerously ignored are the distortions in the allocation of bank credit to the real economy that these risk weighted capital requirements for banks cause.
Thursday, July 13, 2017
Bank regulators, the Basel Committee, FSB, and other, insist on putting systemic risk on ever-larger doses of steroids
What was the biggest systemic risk we used to refer ages ago? That which Mark Twain described with “The bankers are those who want to lend you an umbrella when the sun shines and take it away as soon as it looks like it is going to rain”. In other words that bankers could be too risk adverse, and therefore not be allocating credit efficiently to the real economy.
But what did regulators do with their risk weighted capital requirements for banks? They told banks to lend out even more the umbrella when the sun shines.
I have written on bank regulations for a long time, not as a regulator, but as a consultant that has walked up and down on Main Street helping corporations of all types to access that bank credit that seems so impossible or so expensive when one is perceived as risky.
And as an Executive Director of the World Bank 2002-2004 I also raised my voice on many related issues. You can read some of my public opinions here.
Today I was made aware of a paper from the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, IIASA, authored by Sebastian Poledna, Olaf Bochmann, Stefan Thurner and that is said to suggest: “smart transaction taxes based on the level of systemic risk”
Holy Moly, when will they ever learn? All intrusions that tilt regulations in favor of something or someone become, immediately, a new source of systemic risk?
And the more and the better you are in guarding against some identified systemic risk, the higher you are climbing up the very dangerous mountain.
In April 2003, when commenting on the World Bank's Strategic Framework 04-06 I held: "A mixture of thousand solutions, many of them inadequate, may lead to a flexible world that can bend with the storms. A world obsessed with Best Practices may calcify its structure and break with any small wind."
Everywhere I look I see more and more sources of systemic risks in our banking system. Like which?
Continuing to rely on too few human fallible and capturable credit rating agencies.
Continuing to use risk weighted capital requirements that distort for no good reason at all.
Liquidity requirements that can only increase the distortions.
Forcing the use of standardized risk weights, which imposes a single set of criteria on too many.
Regulators now wanting to assure that banks all apply similar approved risk models.
The stress tests of the stresses that are a la mode.
Living wills.
And of course that pure ideological interference that have statist regulators assigning a 0% risk weight to sovereign and a 100% to citizens.
All in all, in terms of creating dangerous systemic risks, hubris filled bank regulators are the undisputable champions.
The main cause for all this is that our bank regulators seem to find it more glamorous to concern themselves with trying to be better bankers, than with being better regulators.
Regulators, let the banks be banks, perceive the risks and manage the risks. The faster a bank fails if its bankers cannot be good bankers, the better for all. Your responsibility is solely related to what to do when banks fail to be good banks. Please?
And regulators always remember these two rules of thumb:
1. The safer something is perceived to be, the more dangerous to the system it gets; and the riskier it is perceived, the less dangerous for the system it becomes.
2. All good risk management must begin by clearly identifying what risk can we not afford not to take. In banking the risk banks take when allocating credit to the real economy is precisely that kind of risks we cannot afford them not to take.
So when can we get bank regulators humble enough to understand their role is to regulate banks against risks they themselves cannot understand? Please?
Thursday, June 8, 2017
A safer banking system compared to our current dangerously misregulated one with so many systemic risks on steroids
What is a safer banking system?
One in which thousand banks compete and those not able to do so fail as fast as possible, before some major damage has been done, while even, as John Kenneth Galbraith explained, often leaving something good in their wake.
One in which thousand banks compete and those not able to do so fail as fast as possible, before some major damage has been done, while even, as John Kenneth Galbraith explained, often leaving something good in their wake.
What is a dangerous banking system?
One were all banks are explicitly or implicitly supported, by taxpayers, as long as they follow one standard mode that includes living wills, stress tests, risk models, credit ratings, standardized risk weights... all potential sources of dangerous systemic risks.
A bank system in which whenever there is a major problem, the can gets kicked down the road with QEs and there is no cleaning up, and banks just get bigger and bigger.
One that make it more plausible that the banks will all come crashing down on us, at the same time, with excessive exposures to something ex ante perceived safe that ex-post turned out risky, and therefore the banks holding especially little capital.
One were all banks are explicitly or implicitly supported, by taxpayers, as long as they follow one standard mode that includes living wills, stress tests, risk models, credit ratings, standardized risk weights... all potential sources of dangerous systemic risks.
A bank system in which whenever there is a major problem, the can gets kicked down the road with QEs and there is no cleaning up, and banks just get bigger and bigger.
One that make it more plausible that the banks will all come crashing down on us, at the same time, with excessive exposures to something ex ante perceived safe that ex-post turned out risky, and therefore the banks holding especially little capital.
But you don’t worry; the regulators have it all under control with their Dodd-Frank’s Orderly Liquidation Authority (OLA). “Orderly”? Really?
So that is why when I hear about banks “cheating” with their risk models I am not too upset, since that at least introduces some diversity.
Also that cheating stops, at least for a while, the Basel Committee regulators from imposing their loony standardized risk weights of 20% for what has an AAA rating, and so therefore could be utterly dangerous to the system; and one of 150% for the innocuous below BB- rated that bankers don’t like to touch with a ten feet pole.
How did we end up here? That is where you are bound to end up if you allow some statist technocrats, full of hubris, to gather in a mutual admiration club, and there engage into some intellectually degenerating incestuous groupthink.
Statist? What would you otherwise call those who assign a 0% risk weight to the Sovereign and one of 100% to the citizen?
Purposeless? “A ship in harbor is safe, but that is not what ships are for”, John A Shedd
And it is all so purposeless and useless!
Useless? “May God defend me from my friends, I can defend myself from my enemies”, Voltaire
In essence it means that while waiting for all banks to succumb because of lack of oxygen in the last overpopulated safe-haven available, banks will no longer finance the "riskier" future our grandchildren need is financed, but only refinance the "safer" present and past.
In April 2003, as an Executive Director of the World Bank I argued: "A mixture of thousand solutions, many of them inadequate, may lead to a flexible world that can bend with the storms. A world obsessed with Best Practices may calcify its structure and break with any small wind."
PS. FDIC... please don't go there!
Note: For your info, before 1988, we had about 600 years of banking without risk weighted capital requirements for banks distorting the allocation of bank credit to the real economy.
PS. The best of the Financial Choice Act is a not distorting, not systemic risks creating, 10% capital requirement for all assets. Its worst? That this is not applied to all banks.
PS. If I were a regulator: Bank capital requirements = 3% for bankers' ineptitude + 7% for unexpected events = 10% on all assets = Financial Choice Act
In April 2003, as an Executive Director of the World Bank I argued: "A mixture of thousand solutions, many of them inadequate, may lead to a flexible world that can bend with the storms. A world obsessed with Best Practices may calcify its structure and break with any small wind."
PS. FDIC... please don't go there!
Note: For your info, before 1988, we had about 600 years of banking without risk weighted capital requirements for banks distorting the allocation of bank credit to the real economy.
PS. The best of the Financial Choice Act is a not distorting, not systemic risks creating, 10% capital requirement for all assets. Its worst? That this is not applied to all banks.
PS. If I were a regulator: Bank capital requirements = 3% for bankers' ineptitude + 7% for unexpected events = 10% on all assets = Financial Choice Act
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)