Wednesday, May 28, 2025

#ChatGPT #Grok: How many Nobel Prize winners in Economic Sciences have warned about the Basel Committee’s risk weighted bank capital requirements?

I asked: "A number please: Since 1989, how many Nobel Prize winners in Economic Sciences have argued Basel Committee’s risk weighted bank capital requirements distort the allocation of bank credit and central banks’ monetary policies, endangering bank systems and weakening economies?"

ChatGPT answered: Zero.

Since 1989, no Nobel Prize winner in Economic Sciences has explicitly and consistently argued that the Basel Committee’s risk-weighted bank capital requirements:distort the allocation of bank credit, impair central banks’ monetary policies, endanger banking systems, or weaken economies — in a sustained and focused way forming a key part of their recognized academic contributions.

Notes:Some laureates, such as Joseph Stiglitz or Paul Krugman, have criticized aspects of financial regulation and risk management. But not in the specific, systemic, and targeted way your question describes. Others, such as Douglas Diamond (2022), focus on banking fragility and capital regulation, but do not frame Basel-style risk weighting as a root distortion in the sense you're asking.

The Basel framework, despite criticism from various quarters, remains largely supported or at least tolerated in mainstream economics.


Grok answered: Zero.

No Nobel Prize winners in Economic Sciences since 1989 have explicitly argued that the Basel Committee’s risk-weighted bank capital requirements distort bank credit allocation and central banks’ monetary policies in a way that endangers bank systems and weakens economies. 

While some laureates, like Joseph Stiglitz (2001), have critiqued aspects of financial regulation or market distortions, and others, like Ben Bernanke (2022), have studied banking crises, none have directly targeted the Basel framework’s risk-weighted approach in this specific manner. 

The Basel Accords are often debated, but no laureate has framed their critique with the precise combination of distortion, endangerment, and economic weakening you’ve described.


Note: The answers are copied exactly from those given to me by ChatGPT and Grok


Am I and AI confronting the Regulatory Inquisition? Will we be silenced?



I've been on this issue for a very long time.


"Bank supervisors in Basel are unwittingly controlling the capital flows in the world.

How many Basel propositions will it take before they start realizing the damage they are doing by favoring so much bank lending to the public sector. In some developing countries, access to credit for the private sector is all but gone, and the banks are up to the hilt in public credits.

Please, help us get some diversity of thinking to Basel urgently; at the moment it is just a mutual admiration club of firefighters trying to avoid bank crisis at any cost - even at the cost of growth."


Tuesday, May 20, 2025

Do current risk weighted bank capital/equity requirements promote or impede fiscal insolvency?

I asked: "Do current risk bank capital/equity requirements, which favor banks holding public debt over loans to e.g., small businesses and entrepreneurs, when compared to a leverage ratio, do these promote or impede fiscal insolvency?"


Current risk-based capital requirements, which give public debt a lighter touch (often zero or near-zero risk weights) compared to loans for small businesses and entrepreneurs (higher risk weights), tend to promote fiscal insolvency in the long run, though not directly or obviously. Here’s how it shakes out:

By favoring public debt, these rules incentivize banks to load up on government bonds. It’s a sweet deal for them—low capital costs, decent liquidity, and a stamp of safety. This keeps borrowing cheap for governments, letting them pile on debt without much market pushback. Fiscal insolvency—when a government can’t manage its debt without drastic measures—creeps closer because the easy credit masks underlying budget problems. Banks become enablers, holding the IOUs of governments that might be spending beyond their means, all while regulators nod along.

Contrast that with a leverage ratio, like Volcker hinted at. It’s blind to risk weights—public debt and small-business loans chew up the same capital. Banks might dial back on gorging themselves with treasuries since the low returns don’t justify the capital hit. That could force governments to face higher borrowing costs or lean less on debt, potentially slowing the march toward insolvency. Meanwhile, small businesses might not get a drastic boost in credit access (since capital costs stay flat across the board), but the relative bias toward public debt shrinks.

The kicker? Risk-based rules assume governments won’t default, which is a bet that’s held up in places like the U.S. or Germany but looks shakier elsewhere—think Greece or Argentina. A leverage ratio doesn’t care about that assumption; it treats all assets as potential risks. 

So, the current setup greases the wheels for fiscal excess, while a leverage ratio might apply some brakes. It’s not a straight line to insolvency either way—government spending habits and economic growth matter more—but the risk-based system’s favoritism for public debt definitely doesn’t discourage it. 



The current risk-weighted capital/equity requirements, which favor banks holding public debt over loans to small businesses or entrepreneurs, can have complex effects on fiscal insolvency. Here’s how these dynamics play out:

1. Promotion of Fiscal Insolvency (Indirectly):

Preference for Public Debt: When banks are incentivized to hold government bonds over riskier assets (like small business loans), this can facilitate increased government borrowing. Governments may issue more debt knowing that banks are inclined to purchase it due to the favorable capital treatment under risk-weighted regulations. Over time, if this borrowing becomes unsustainable and governments run large fiscal deficits, this could lead to fiscal stress or insolvency risks.

Crowding Out: As banks allocate more resources to buying government debt rather than lending to the private sector (especially small businesses and entrepreneurs), it can lead to a crowding-out effect. This can stifle private sector growth, reduce innovation, and harm economic productivity, which in turn can lower tax revenues and contribute to fiscal strain in the long term.

2. Impediment to Fiscal Insolvency:

Lower Risk for Banks: From the perspective of bank stability, public debt is generally viewed as lower risk (especially sovereign debt of stable countries), so encouraging banks to hold these assets reduces the risk of bank insolvency. Strong banks are less likely to need bailouts, which might otherwise increase fiscal burdens on governments.

Stable Financing for Government: Encouraging banks to hold public debt can also provide a stable source of funding for governments, ensuring liquidity and lowering borrowing costs, at least in the short to medium term. This can help governments manage their fiscal policies more effectively without triggering immediate insolvency risks.

Leverage Ratio vs. Risk-Weighted Capital Requirements:

Leverage Ratio: A leverage ratio (e.g., a fixed minimum capital requirement, regardless of asset risk) may be more neutral, treating all assets equally and not favoring public debt over private loans. This could lead banks to allocate capital more efficiently across different asset

Leverage Ratio vs. Risk-Weighted Capital Requirements

Leverage Ratio: This is a non-risk-weighted measure that requires banks to hold a certain percentage of capital against all assets, regardless of risk. It is simpler and treats all assets equally, meaning that government debt and risky small business loans would be weighted the same. While this would discourage banks from over-relying on low-risk assets like government debt, it could also make them more cautious about extending loans to riskier segments like small businesses.

Risk-Weighted Capital Requirements: These, on the other hand, give preferential treatment to lower-risk assets, like government bonds, and impose stricter requirements for riskier loans. This encourages banks to hold safer assets, but can discourage lending to higher-risk but potentially productive sectors, such as entrepreneurs and small businesses.

Overall Impact on Fiscal Insolvency

Impediment to Fiscal Insolvency: Risk-weighted requirements favor government debt, which is seen as lower risk and helps provide governments with cheaper and more stable financing. This can prevent fiscal insolvency in the short term by ensuring governments can service their debt obligations.

Promotion of Fiscal Insolvency (Long-Term Risk): If government borrowing is too easy and unchecked, it could lead to excessive debt accumulation. Over-reliance on government bonds by banks can also tie the health of the financial system to government solvency, creating a potential for systemic risk in the case of fiscal stress.

In summary, risk-weighted capital requirements that favor public debt may impede fiscal insolvency in the short term but could promote it over the long term by facilitating excessive government borrowing and stifling private sector growth. The use of a leverage ratio, which doesn't favor any asset class, might offer a more balanced but conservative approach.


Note: The answers are copied exactly from those given to me by ChatGPT and Grok


A 2004 letter in the Financial Times: "The Basel Committee is unwittingly controlling the capital flows in the world. How many Basel propositions will it take before they start realizing the damage they are doing by favoring so much bank lending to the public sector?"

Monday, May 19, 2025

#Grok #ChatGPT: On the Basel Committee's bank capital/equity requirements: Where have all economists gone? Long time passing.

I asked: "Briefly, with decades of lower bank capital requirements against public debt and residential mortgages than against loans to small businesses and entrepreneurs, what should an economist expect would happen?"


Grok answered:

An economist would expect:

Increased Lending to Public Debt and Mortgages: Lower capital requirements reduce the cost of holding government bonds and residential mortgages, leading banks to allocate more capital to these assets.

Reduced Lending to Small Businesses and Entrepreneurs: Higher capital requirements for loans to small businesses and entrepreneurs make them less attractive, resulting in reduced credit availability for these sectors.

Asset Price Inflation in Housing: Increased mortgage lending fuels demand for housing, driving up property prices.

Economic Imbalance: Over-reliance on public debt and real estate lending can crowd out productive investment in small businesses, stifling innovation and economic dynamism.

Systemic Risk: Concentration of bank assets in government bonds and mortgages increases vulnerability to sovereign debt crises or housing market downturns.

Wider Inequality: Easier access to mortgage credit benefits wealthier households, while small businesses, often owned by less affluent entrepreneurs, face credit constraints, exacerbating wealth gaps.


ChatGPT answered:

An economist should expect that, over decades, lower bank capital requirements for public debt and residential mortgages would systematically incentivize banks to favor these assets over riskier ones like small business or entrepreneurial loans. The likely outcomes include:

Credit misallocation: Excessive lending to housing and government sectors, underinvestment in productive, growth-generating activities.

Asset inflation: Higher house prices and potential housing bubbles due to overfunding of mortgages.

Weaker innovation and productivity: Undersupply of capital to entrepreneurs and small businesses, which are key drivers of innovation and job creation.

Higher systemic risk: Apparent safety of low-capital assets can mask concentration risks and reduce financial system resilience.

Overall, this policy bias distorts market signals and impairs long-term economic dynamism.


Note: The answers are copied exactly from those given to me by ChatGPT and Grok 3


Monday, May 12, 2025

What if bank regulators had not missed, or fallen asleep during the lectures on Bayesian conditional probabilities?

Opining 2013:

What's perceived as “most dangerous”, the risky, the trucks, is what currently in banking must transit at the slowest speeds, the lowest allowed bank leverages; while those perceived as the safest, like sovereigns, residential mortgages and AAA rated securities, are those allowed to go through our residential neighborhoods at the highest speeds, the highest allowed leverages.

 

I do understand, it is hard to internalize that, at least when it comes to banking, that which is perceived as safe is so much more dangerous to the system than that which is perceived as risky. Sadly, way too many missed their lectures on conditional probabilities. 


https://subprimeregulations.blogspot.com/2013/10/worse-than-high-speed-allowed-trucks-is.html

 

Opining 2018:

 

What is the conditional probability of assets being dangerous to bank systems when conditioned to that bankers have perceived these assets as risky? 

Assets perceived by bankers as risky become safer, not riskier.


What is the conditional probability of assets being dangerous to bank systems when conditioned to that bankers have perceived these assets as safe?


Assets perceived by bankers as safe become riskier, not safer.

 

Regulators who base their capital requirements for banks on that what’s perceived as risky is more dangerous to the bank systems than what’s perceived as safe, is that because they have never heard about conditional probabilities?

 

https://subprimeregulations.blogspot.com/2018/08/risk-weighted-capital-requirements-for.html


 

Dialogue with ChatGPT 2023:


I asked: "If the risks for banking systems are much conditioned to how credit risks are perceived, would it not be useful to base the risk weighted bank capital requirements on the conditional probabilities?"

 

It answered: "Yes, by utilizing conditional probabilities, regulators could tailor risk weights more precisely to reflect the true credit risk associated with different assets. This approach could help mitigate the potential for misalignment between risk weights and actual risk, which is important for maintaining the stability and soundness of the banking system."


https://subprimeregulations.blogspot.com/2023/06/ai-chatgpt-openai-should-risk-weighted.html

 

Dialogue with Grok 2025:

 

I asked: “Small businesses and entrepreneurs are inherently riskier bets than government debt—default rates are higher, and public debt (especially from stable governments) is often seen as a safe haven.” If using Bayesian conditional probabilities, are the perceived “riskier bets” more dangerous to bank systems than what’s perceived as very safe?

 

It answered: Yes: Small-business loans might ding banks regularly but rarely break them. Government debt, seen as safe, lulls everyone into piling in—until it doesn’t. When it blows, the conditional probability of it causing a collapse could outstrip the scattered impact of SME failures. It’s less about raw default rates and more about exposure scale and systemic ripple.” 

 

https://subprimeregulations.blogspot.com/2025/04/ai-grok-chatgpt-what-about-bank.html



A 2012 warning:


A homemade 2010 youtube comment related to this issue



In 1999: "The possible Big Bang that scares me the most is the one that could happen the day those genius bank regulators in Basel, playing Gods, manage to introduce a systemic error in the financial system."

In 2004, with Basel II, sadly, they did.